Quick Disclaimer
The following is a transcript of recorded content. Please note, these transcripts are not always perfect and may contain typos. If you notice any major mistakes, please feel free to report them by opening a Technical Support ticket under the Help menu at the top of the screen.
Full Transcript
Chris Martenson: Welcome everyone to this Featured Voices podcast being hosted at PeakProsperity.com. I’m your host, Christ Martenson. And it is July 23rd, 2019. As of today, the world’s central banks are thoroughly out of fresh ideas and that’s if they had any to begin with. There’s always–you know there always has to be some sort of relationship, right, between the economy–maybe as measured by the GDP and the claims on the economic output. And this is something a lot of people forget about–stocks, bonds, currency–those are all claims on the economic output. In particular, future economic output. Now, central banks–they’re very good at creating asset price inflation which they have done massively in the past 10 years. Stocks at record highs are close to them, bonds are record low yields which means record high prices. So mind-bogglingly off the reservation that there are, even as of today, European junk rated companies whose bonds are trading with negative yields. Now if you can’t make any sense of that sentence, don’t worry–that means you’re normal. But the central bankers this is all somehow explicable and can be rationalized away. But can it?
And what if the recent calls in the U.S. political debates for modern monetary theory or MMT injections a freshly printed currency handed out to the people this time instead of to the banks? After 10 years of printing and mispricing money and fostering a massive surge in the levels of debt all the central bankers have got to show for their efforts are–low to nonexistent to even negative rates of economic growth and an enormous largest ever wealth and income gap. Hardly the sort of inspirational outcome they were hoping for–presumably.
So, they keep going more of the same in hopes it will all turn around soon enough. But what if their basic models are wrong. What if the core tenets of the economists currently running the monetary show are simply wrong? Even worse in my mind is that the entire model of growth is now a significant danger to our futures and there are no mainstream economists even questioning that despite all the ecological disruption that we see and that of course goes hand in hand with too fast rates of resource extraction.
Infinite growth was never a possibility on a finite planet. We are now bumping into that reality but it’s not part of the larger dialogue. Well, if the central bankers have the models all wrong and are pursuing destructive growth then a very large financial catastrophe is not only a possible outcome but a likely if not, assured outcome. Which means, there’s literally nothing quite as important to your financial, if not physical future as understanding economics and what the central bankers are intending to do and why.
Today’s guest is the perfect individual to help us sort out what’s going on and what the true risks are in this story. Professor Steve Keen is an Australian economist and author. He’s a post-Keynesian who includes debt in his models. I know, what a rebel. And criticizes neoclassical economics as inconsistent, unscientific and empirically unsupported. And of course he’s being very kind in phrasing it that way. He’s the author of the book, Debunking Economics and hosts the popular blog debtdeflation.com. I’m really excited to have him bank on the program. I got 100 questions. Welcome, Professor Steve Keen.
Steve Keen: Thank you very much. I would actually just clarify one thing. I am now actually the–the debt deflation is sort of active, but the main way that I post these days is on my crowdfunding site on Patreon, which is at patreon.com/ProfSteveKeen.
Chris Martenson: Yes. I’ve noticed that and I want to get that on the backend because I think what you’re doing is super important around that. But let’s dive right in. Hey, Steve, what have the mainstream economists got wrong?
Steve Keen: Do you want to rephrase the question–what have they got right?
Chris Martenson: Yes. What have they got right?
Steve Keen: Yeah. Okay, now I’m struggling.
Chris Martenson:Everything and nothing is a perfect set of answers.
Steve Keen: What they’ve got right is a way of thinking about reality that makes everything look like it’s honky dory. And in that sense there is an ideological defense for the current–for the status quo when it is a completely inaccurate description of that status quo. And that’s what most disturbs me. I think you can make enormous arguments for capitalism in the sense of an engine of innovation, of growth and dynamism and change. And that is entirely what they haven’t done. They instead said it is a perfect vehicle for shaving equilibrium and satisfaction of everybody’s utility and–and the lack of any–any social conflict. And they also for the best and pray for an optimal world. You couldn’t get a less accurate description of capitalism. But a bit like the old Ptolemaic theory of astronomy it fits–they tweak the parameters until such stages it appears to fit the past data. But they haven’t got a hope in how they’re working out the future. And in that sense, they are actually jeopardizing our future, which is my main focus today.
Chris Martenson: Well, I really want to get to that. I do think they are jeopardizing the future but let me back up. So, I said you had criticized neoclassical economics as–as inconsistent, unscientific, empirically unsupported. Look, you know, one of the things that they are saying right now is that they are driving rates down because they want to spur growth. But I can crank up any old you know, 15 year long chart of GDP and discover a downward trend. Isn’t that enough data to say maybe that whatever they’re doing needs a tweak?
Steve Keen: Oh, the data is just overwhelming against their arguments completely, Chris. This is–data, they massage data through what’s called econometrics and there’s an excellent old paper by a guy called Ed Leamar called Taking the Con out of Econometrics. And if you read it is quite possible to fit these models which are fundamentally the economists–econometricians in general mainly linearly squares type modeling. And if you have enough variables and enough tweaking of the parameters and assume everything is normally distributed in the error term you can fit the data into the trends so you don’t have any data model changes. So they really are free of data.
And I’ll give my favorite example of that–everybody is saying the classic old textbook of downward sloping demand curve the higher the price, the less the demand. The lower the price the more the demand and a rising supply curve. Now, the rising supply curve you know, which makes in some ways you want more of something you gotta pay more for it that is the gut appeal it has for most people. When you take a look at how they logically derive that, they assume that there is a level of fixed capital stock which they call a fixed resource and a variable input – mainly labor, and they say you have an increasing amount of labor rather than for capital, then you might initially get an increase in per work or productivity then you get a falling level of productivity and they call this diminishing marginal productivity.
Now, when you go and research actual firms and ask what is the slope of your supply curve was with this theory of diminishing marginal productivity they get a rising supply curve. That’s the entire foundation of that rise in curve in the literature. They say that the short run costs–not their long run–their short run costs fall with output. The more output the lower the cost per unit. Both in terms of falling fixed costs and often a rising efficiency of the–of their use of variable capacity. And economists completely ignore this. In fact, the key paper if you most people know from Milton Friedman about methodology called The Methodology of Positive Economics is literally written to say don’t bother reading the empirical papers in the American Economic Review about the actual cost structures of firms. So there’s–there’s a foundational belief the rising supply curve, you do your empirical research and found for most firms it’s a falling supply curve. Does it show up in the textbooks? No. And it’s even after one of the most recent people to find this empirical irregularity compared to the theory was Alan Blinder, who was actually the Vice President of the Federal Reserve and vice president of the American Economic Association.
Even when some like him finds it the results just get varied. So, they couldn’t give a damn about empirical data and unfortunate empirical data couldn’t give a damn about them, either.
Chris Martenson: Well, let me give you one of my favorite examples and that is a great one. Recently, I’ve seen both the ECB and the U.S. Federal Reserve come out and claim openly that their policies are not at all responsible for whatever wealth gaps exist at this point in time. And I struggle with that greatly, Steve because it’s completely obvious to me what the transmission mechanism is if you throw money into financial markets and those markets go up and the primary holders of those assets happen to be rich people–they get richer. How could that even remotely be up for debate?
Steve Keen: Yeah, I know. In fact, it is rather disingenuous because if you read Bernanke’s statements on the idea of stimulating the stock market, stimulating asset markets it was because he called it the wealth effect. He thought that people get wealthier they are more likely to spend more and stimulate the economy. Now, you don’t get a wealth effect unless you make people wealthier. So, the purpose of QE was to increase asset prices. A simple way that I describe it, leaving out the leverage that applies when you buy shares as well, QE was a trillion dollars a year in the United States roughly. The Federal Reserve declared they were on the buy side of market operations to the tune of a $80 million per month, which is pretty much a trillion dollars per year.
That means every year, simply by an accounting operation the federal reserve is putting a trillion dollars into the bank accounts of financial institutions in return for a trillion dollars’ worth of bonds out of the books of the Federal Reserve. Now if you look upon the financial companies can do–by law a financial company must buy financial assets, they have to cover the costs of operation as well. But primarily, they buy financial assets. If they can’t buy bonds, what are they going to buy? Shares and some property. What’s that going to do to the process of those? A trillion dollars per year–drive the prices up. Even if it’s a simple transfer, so rather than leverage coming into the operation you have increased the value of these shares by a trillion dollars.
Then, when people who own those shares are a trillion dollars richer, they may then sell some of those shares themselves to capitalize the gains and then spend some of that money into the real economy. So, maybe the trillion dollars if you include all the bankers’ fees and the wages they pay themselves from which they buy the old Lamborghini–that could be really $100 billion of stimulus into the real economy. But as my great friend Michael Hudson puts it — a wonderful turner of phrases he said the Federal Reserve helicopter falls and lands on Wall Street, not Main Street. So some is linked across but it has dramatically increased inequality. And I think it’s just ludicrous for anybody to claim otherwise. Especially, the architects of this who did it because of what they call the “wealth effect.”
Chris Martenson: We are going to increase the wealth effect but trust us it’s not going to actually drive a wealth gap. Yeah–there is some hocus pocus in between those two statements, of course. And it is disingenuous and self-serving. But the thing that, I guess, drives me nuts is not only A. do they feel comfortable saying it but B, I don’t see them challenged by the financial press. You know, nobody ever asks the follow up question or the financial services in–in congress. Nobody asks a follow up question. How can you even say that? Right?
Steve Keen: Yeah, I know. They just get away with it. This where when you see how Greenspan in particular managed to make obscurity into a–a marketing vehicle by making comments that you know, completely bamboozle everybody listening, including himself. But the aura of mystique about them and there are plenty of studies to show the extent to which the federal reserve dominates academic funding. And of course, also for journalists. I pine for the days when you had investigative journalists being primarily hired by newspapers these days because the newspapers completely blew the model of the internet. They are all basically on life support. And the easiest thing they can do is they have these press releases. If you come up with some critical–if you criticize the press releases, you might not get the next press release or the next solicitation with the person releasing it. And that might have given us a very obsequious media when it comes to examining the actions of the officials like the Federal Reserve chiefs.
Chris Martenson: This is ancient history, of course, because it goes all the way back to Janet Yellen so we might as well be discussing Mongolian times under Genghis Khan. Remember Janet Yellen was actually asked a follow up question by a journalist once about some very devious insider stuff that happened at the Federal Reserve, where they were inappropriately communicating with a financial firm. And that person was kicked out and never invited back to another Federal Reserve press conference. It was a public hanging as we call it in the business world. Where all the other journalists took note of that and said oh I don’t want that to be me. And they got away with it, too. I was quite surprised.
Steve Keen: Trump does a similar thing in the White House, which we all see and object to. But of course, the Federal Reserve is doing exactly the same bloody thing.
Chris Martenson: All right, Steve, I need you to get out your neoclassical decoder ring because a lot of my listeners are very confused by when the Fed says the inflation is too low. They say it, they say it and then the press doesn’t even follow up with that. It simply repeats it. But I can imagine the common person needs a little bit of explanation for that policy. So why should explain to us now why should the common person want rising instead of falling prices for things? You know, what does the Fed really mean here? Because they can’t really mean that people want rising prices. None of us do. But they do. Why is that?
Steve Keen: That is actually two–you got two questions conflated there. So, I’ll just pull back and say one. Why would the ordinary person want rising prices? Irving Fisher answered that very well during the Great Depression. Because he said what caused the Great Depression was a disequilibrium event. He was very specific that it was not equilibrium. He couldn’t realize his mistake to see it coming was by thinking the financial markets are an equilibrium factor of the economy. He said, what the disequilibrium events cause the crisis of too much lift at its beginning and too low rate of inflation at the same time. And he then said what can happen with that is when people try to liquidate, particularly businesses, when they try to liquidate their stocks to reduce their debt, the liquidation drives down prices. They then pay the debt off that they have in nominal terms but the decline in GDP can actually be bigger than the amount of debt that they pay down, and what you therefore see is the phenomenon of a falling level of debt in absolute terms but a rising level of debt to GDP. And when I don’t know that Fisher had access to the same data that I’ve got now on what actually on that happened in 1933. But if you take a look at the data what you normally see there is a huge increase after 36 in the ratio of private debt to GDP in America. And that sort of what everybody focuses upon. When you look at the actual data, you see that across that period of time debt was falling in nominal terms at the rate of something like 5 or 10% per annum. But the GDP was falling by 20 to 25%, 10 to 15 from the real decline in output and 10% from the fall in CPI. So that you do not want to be in that circumstance. And if you don’t actually have bankruptcy laws and you don’t have things like the New Deal and stuff coming in. The end product that was always in economy was zero GDP. It is just overruns everything and nobody produces anything.
So, that’s the reason an ordinary person even has an interest in it because if there is debt, if we have private debt in the economy and we do–then we don’t want to have the rate of inflation so low that that danger is a possibility and that is why I am generally saying that a bit of inflation is a good thing because the inflation itself is the increase in nominal values is reducing the debt burden of the also nominal debt you have at the same time. So that is what I see as the realistic case for it. I’ll give you, yeah.
Chris Martenson: Please, if you want to continue the thought–please do.
Steve Keen: Yeah. Well, what did the Fed do about it. The Fed is a typical outpost of neoclassical mainstream economics. They do what they call dynamics to cast to equilibrium models these days. And the models are extremely complicated. They are not complex. They are complicated. The atomic astronomy analogy comes to mind. The atomic model of the solar system is incredibly complicated but not complex.
And in that model that had three magic numbers. There is a 2% rate of inflation, a 3% rate of economic growth and a 4% rate of interest. And those–those numbers are almost hardwired into all these models. And that is why think we should be above 2% so we can actually impose high interest rates to bring it down. But of course, what they are finding themselves now is below the 2% rate and have no idea how to pump it up and very effectively unintentional, of course, in the last 10 years.
Chris Martenson: So, looking back at that data you talked about yes, I see that big bump in debt to GDP starting at 29 to 35 or so, right? And as you mentioned that bump isn’t because we are taking on lots more debt. It’s because GDP was falling faster than debt at that moment in time. But since the 1970’s we’ve had this whole financialization kick. And we do have rising debt to GDP. And that’s because debt is now compounding at a faster rate than even nominal GDP. And that is what I think has been enshrined at the central banks is how things are supposed to work. But isn’t there a math problem sort of baked into that? You can’t grow the claims faster than the economy forever, can you?
Steve Keen: No. If you look at the data you got to break it down into all different types of debt, as well, Chris, we can defer that to later. But if you look at the level of private debt that in America’s case rose from about–I’ll bring up the numbers as we speak. Should have brought this up earlier one of my documents to see the number back in the Great Depression period. But if debt, private debt in America began right after the Second World War went to 30 to 40% of GDP. It rose to 170% shortly the peaking shortly after the financial crisis. And then it has fallen to 150% of GDP and it’s now flatlining about that level. It is actually as a percentage of GDP falling a bit right now. So, what you had is the whole period up to 2007 was an increasingly credit fueled bubble where change in debt, which is what creates credit, was positive and therefore that gave you additional demand and that argument by the way sets me outside the mainstream completely. But the additional demand came at the expense of accumulating more debt. You can keep on doing it over such time that people are no longer willing to take the debt on. They felt to belaboured to begin with. Too many debt financed projects fell over. The Ponzi schemes suffered the subprime market coming home to roost. All that happened and that’s the end of the bubble. What you’re left with is an enormous level of private debt that, it can sequel on literally for decades.
And in the case of Japan, Japan went through exactly the same process 20 years before America with its bubble economy bursting in 1990–when it burst, its peak level of debt 225% of GDP–that’s private debt. It’s now at 170%. Of course, we all know that Japan has had extremely sluggish growth to negative growth through all that time period. And what I said when I saw a financial crisis coming is we are all going to turn Japanese. And that’s the state of the American economy is in right now.
Chris Martenson: Well, Japan though. I mean if we said listen, the economy there is to serve the people not the other way around and in this case I think when we’re talking central banks we talked about the economy but they’re really talking about the banking system. I think the economy is a derivative of that. They care that they have a stable banking system. So, I can make a strong case for why Japan ought to have a falling GDP, right? They got they are losing population. And the population that remains is aging rapidly, as on a demographic basis. So, to me that says hey, Japan should have a falling economy but the system of banking can’t stand that. Isn’t there a conflict there when you have a — an infinite growth, perpetual growth based banking system and we can discuss whether or not that has to be true. But it seems to be true, right?
Steve Keen: I agree with that. And the, but the thing is Japan’s growth didn’t stop when it had the demographic crisis. Japan’s growth stopped on a dime on the 31st of December 1989 when the bubble economy burst, at which point the Nika was almost 40,000 points and it finally fell to about 7. It wasn’t the demographics that took the wind out of the economy. It was the collapse in the financial sector. But the demographic system because it is a declining level of the population has actually softened the blow. And that–that is something that is actually advantageous with a falling population.
Chris Martenson: Well, you know a lot of your work is really informed by thinking over time and one of the seminal pieces was just that simple spreadsheet with the math you showed that said listen, if a government is or if your credit growth let’s start at the highest level. If your aggregate credit growth in an economy is 10% and next year it is still 10%, that sounds awesome. But in fact, that’s actually GDP neutral to negative depending on–on where we are at in the model because once you get locked into a rising credit market and you are using credit to fuel GDP growth, then the credit growth has to increase on a constant basis or it becomes negative. Have I captured that even remotely correct?
Steve Keen: Pretty much. The part that sets me apart from mainstream economists and even most Keynesian colleagues is that I was arguing for a long time the total amount of the economy is income plus change in debt. Now, strictly speaking–that’s not true. What’s the case the demand is turn over existing money plus change in debt. And if you look at most–the reason I was still right with a strictly wrong argument empirically generally right is that most debt that is taken on these days is to buy assets. So, if you have like a 100% of debt purchases or credit purchases were to buy existing assets exactly subprime in the telecommunications bubble beforehand it would be true–the total amount of the economy summing together both the real economy and the financial world would be income plus change in debt.
What you find in the real world is it is turn over existing money plus change in debt. Now, if credit, which is change in debt, is a massive part of your demand, then if it is running at 10 and 15% per annum, it’s going to be growing faster than your GDP. You’re going to require continuing growing at that speed or they will be given large credit comes relative to actual production there will be a huge slump in demand. And of course that’s what happened. So, you can actually have a financial crisis in your economy simply the rate of exchange of debt slows down–it doesn’t have to go negative. But of course, it does normally go negative and the United States case, for example, in the 2008 crisis the rate of change of private debt–which is credit–peaked at just over 15% of GDP back in mid-2006 and by the end of 2010 it was down to -5% of GDP. So, that’s a switch from positive to negative credit is what really gives a financial crisis like 2008 and, like the Great Depression, their sting.
Chris Martenson: Now, is that a similar concept as the credit impulse which people talked about?
Steve Keen: Yes. It’s two fold–it’s quite complicated, which is not amazing. But the basic story is debt itself will rise if the change in debt exceeds the change in GDP. And then, when you look at what’s happening with things like the asset market, the demand for assets is largely leveraged amount. So, it actually is determining how many physical shares or physical houses you can buy is the new debt, which is the change in debt divided by the price level. You then get a relationship between what is causing change in price level it’s the change in the change in new debt or change in the change in debt. So, that’s where the credit accelerator comes in. It actually should be called the debt accelerator because it’s the second–second derivative of debt that matters for driving asset prices up or down.
Chris Martenson: This is a–
Steve Keen: Hope I haven’t lost to many of your listeners with that one.
Chris Martenson: I’m sure they’ll follow along. We’ll put a nice transcript under there as well so they can parse it out at their own pace if they want. This is a global economy at this point in time. Clearly, I mean we had a curious case very early this year where Apple released some negative earnings results and within a matter of minutes we saw the New Zealand dollar tanking against the Yen as a consequence. So, it’s this highly interlinked computerized system. Feels like it needs to stay global. What are the chances that the current trade spat with the United States, that this global sloshing of money and a big portion of that coming out of China, what’s the chance that there could be a seizure in the system because the global flow has suddenly reversed course?
Steve Keen: That’s quite feasible. I don’t see an economic crisis coming this time around, as I did last time. But because I to have an economic crisis you have to have a high level of private debt change credit and that’s very negative–positive to negative. You’ve got sort of the anemic level of aggregate, of credit in the United States and most of the rest of the world, that is not going to occur. But you do have financial institutions which are very dependent upon the continued government funding, the QE and so on, who have got lots of bad loans accumulating with the private sector on their books that are masked to some extent by the positive benefit that they are getting out of the Federal Reserve’s intervention. So if that intervention falters at any time, that suddenly in–in Warren Buffet’s wonderful phrase–makes the tide go out and you can see who is naked or not. So, I think a lot of these financial institutions are relatively naked. They are only kept clothed by what the Federal Reserve is doing and therefore, you haven’t got a genuine capitalistic economy here. You’ve got this weird mish mash where a bunch of conventional neoclassical economists are managing something that has got a closer resemblance to the Soviet Union than I’d like to admit.
Chris Martenson: I totally agree. That’s we have a small cabal of unelected people setting the price levels for practically everything. What could go wrong, right?
Steve Keen: Yeah, exactly. Yeah. And I think they are being capitalists about it. That’s what amuses me about these jerks.
Chris Martenson: Yeah, I know. Exactly. So, Steve, we’re talking to you you’re in Europe at the moment, in Amsterdam. So, let’s talk about Europe for a second and just how distorted this all seems to be. The world is honestly, I want to talk about whether debt really matters. There is this emerging view, which I think is wrong, that debt and deficits really don’t seem to matter at this point. And again, to focus this down to a–a metaphor if you will-I love this idea that the world’s central banks have managed to coordinate in such a way that Italian ten year debt is trading with a lower yield than U.S. ten year debt which traditional financial theory tells us Italian debt carries less risk than U.S. debt. Obviously, that’s a perversion of the story. So, what’s happening there and–and is it possible that the central banks have now become such dominant players that we can’t actually analyze debt and price levels in debt like we used to?
Steve Keen: I think that’s true. They’ve become so dominant because they have been trying to rescue a system they don’t understand using the tools they have. And those tools, fundamentally that the central banks play with the accounts of private financial sector but not with a real economy. Not with a financial sector. So it is easy to fall into QE. To do the QE the easiest way for it to happen is that the on the central bank’s the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet you got assets, liability and inequity which is rather immaterial for a central bank, crucial for a private one.
But all they have to do to buy a trillion dollars of bonds off the financial sector each year is to say we are going to put a trillion dollars’ worth of money into our liabilities, which is your bank the accounts of private banks at the central bank. We are going to record the trillion dollars’ worth of loans of–of bonds you sold to us in return for money on assets on our balance sheet. Bang, they create the money. And they have unlimited capacity to do that so long as people accept their own national currency for payments and in virtually every part of the world it happens until a complete breakdown occurs. How they can go on doing this indefinitely. And therefore you can’t speculate on the stock market in America without wondering what the Federal Reserve is doing. And keeping a strong eye on any of their policy changes–any trading position whatsoever.
Chris Martenson: Absolutely. It has really become more important to follow what the Fed is doing than any simply fundamental piece. Now changing of the guard and European central bank. We got Mario Drage, who never saw a problem that couldn’t be met with printing being replaced by someone who–and I am just being accurate–not unfair–is, I believe, a convicted felon. So–so they had, they looked long and hard across all of Europe and discovered that Christine LaGarde was probably the best they could possibly find out of everybody who exists. She to me, feels like somebody who the system could count on to basically continue Drage’s policies more than probably a best fit for what the world needs at this point. Would you, you know, peering into that the possible things that might happen would you predict more printing by the ECB than less going forward?
Steve Keen: I think there is no choice but to continue printing and the reason for this is quite simple from my point of view. And that is that the central bank by boosting asset prices as much as it is done has become the fundamental underlier of these asset markets. And as soon as they try to reverse the policy it is happening in states where they wanted go from quantitative easing to quantitative tightening. The market is tanked because you reversed the process. Whereas under QE the Federal Reserve is putting money into your balance sheets and taking out income earning bonds. Therefore, you would actually get a decent return as a fi